• 回答数

    4

  • 浏览数

    147

虎妞1989
首页 > 英语培训 > 亚当斯密斯英文名

4个回答 默认排序
  • 默认排序
  • 按时间排序

有毒的少女

已采纳

Adam Smith (baptised 16 June 1723 – 17 July 1790 [OS: 5 June 1723 – 17 July 1790]) was a Scottish moral philosopher and a pioneer of political economy. One of the key figures of the Scottish Enlightenment, Smith is the author of The Theory of Moral Sentiments and An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. The latter, usually abbreviated as The Wealth of Nations, is considered his magnum opus and the first modern work of economics. Adam Smith is widely cited as the father of modern economics.[1][2]Smith studied moral philosophy at the University of Glasgow and Oxford University. After graduating he delivered a successful series of public lectures at Edinburgh, leading him to collaborate with David Hume during the Scottish Enlightenment. Smith obtained a professorship at Glasgow teaching moral philosophy, and during this time wrote and published The Theory of Moral Sentiments. In his later life he took a tutoring position which allowed him to travel throughout Europe where he met other intellectual leaders of his day. Smith returned home and spent the next ten years writing The Wealth of Nations (mainly from his lecture notes) which was published in 1776. He died in 1790.Biography[edit] Early lifeAdam Smith was born to Margaret Douglas at Kirkcaldy, Fife, Scotland. His father, also named Adam Smith, was a lawyer, civil servant, and widower who married Margaret Douglas in 1720 and died six months before Smith was born.[3] Although the exact date of Smith's birth is unknown, his baptism was recorded on 16 June 1723 at Kirkcaldy.[4] Though few events in Smith's early childhood are known, Scottish journalist and biographer of Smith John Rae recorded that Smith was abducted by gypsies at the age of four and eventually released when others went to rescue him.[note 1] Smith was particularly close to his mother, who likely encouraged him to pursue his scholarly ambitions.[6] He attended the Burgh School of Kirkcaldy – characterised by Rae as "one of the best secondary schools of Scotland at that period" – from 1729 to 1737.[5] There he studied Latin, mathematics, history, and writing.[6][He published The Theory of Moral Sentiments in 1759, embodying some of his Glasgow lectures. This work was concerned with how human morality depends on sympathy between agent and spectator, or the individual and other members of society. He bases his explanation not on a special "moral sense", as the third Lord Shaftesbury and Hutcheson had done, nor on utility as Hume did, but on sympathy. Smith's popularity greatly increased due to the The Theory of Moral Sentiments, and as a result, many wealthy students left their schools in other countries to enroll at Glasgow to learn under Smith.[20]After the publication of The Theory of Moral Sentiments, Smith began to give more attention to jurisprudence and economics in his lectures and less to his theories of morals. The development of his ideas on political economy can be observed from the lecture notes taken down by a student in 1763, and from what William Robert Scott described as an early version of part of The Wealth of Nations.[21] For example, Smith lectured that labor—rather than the nation's quantity of gold or silver—is the cause of increase in national wealth.[20]François Quesnay, one of the leaders of the Physiocratic school of thoughtIn 1762, the academic senate of the University of Glasgow conferred on Smith the title of Doctor of Laws (LL.D.). At the end of 1763, he obtained a lucrative offer from Charles Townshend (who had been introduced to Smith by David Hume) to tutor his stepson, Henry Scott, the young Duke of Buccleuch. Smith subsequently resigned from his professorship to take the tutoring position. Because he resigned in the middle of the term, Smith attempted to return the fees he had collected from his students, but they refused.[22][edit] Tutoring and travelsSmith's tutoring job entailed touring Europe with Henry Scott while teaching him subjects including proper Polish.[22] Smith was paid £300 per year plus expenses along with £300 per year pension, which was roughly twice his former income as a teacher.[22] Smith first traveled as a tutor to Toulouse, France, where he stayed for a year and a half.[22] According to accounts, Smith found Toulouse to be very boring, and he wrote to Hume that he "had begun to write a book in order to pass away the time".[22] After touring the south of France, the group moved to Geneva. While in Geneva, Smith met with the philosopher Voltaire.[23] After staying in Geneva, the party went to Paris.While in Paris, Smith came to know intellectual leaders such as Benjamin Franklin,[24] Turgot, Jean D'Alembert, André Morellet, Helvétius and, in particular, Francois Quesnay, the head of the Physiocratic school, whose academic products he respected greatly.[25] The physiocrats believed that wealth came from production and not from the attainment of precious metals, which was adverse to mercantilist thought. They also believed that agriculture tended to produce wealth and that merchants and manufacturers did not.[24] While Smith did not embrace all of the physiocrats' ideas, he did say that physiocracy was "with all its imperfections [perhaps] the nearest approximation to the truth that has yet been published upon the subject of political economy".[26][edit] Later years and writingsIn 1766, Henry Scott's younger brother died in Paris, and Smith's tour as a tutor ended shortly thereafter.[26] Smith returned home that year to Kirkcaldy, and he devoted much of the next ten years to his magnum opus.[27] There he befriended Henry Moyes, a young blind man who showed precocious aptitude. As well as teaching Moyes himself, Smith secured the patronage of David Hume and Thomas Reid in the young man's education.[28] In May 1773 Smith was elected fellow of the Royal Society of London,[29] and was elected a member of the Literary Club in 1775.[30] The Wealth of Nations was published in 1776 and was an instant success, selling out the first edition in only six months.[31]In 1778 Smith was appointed to a post as commissioner of customs in Scotland and went to live with his mother in Panmure House in Edinburgh's Canongate.[32] Five years later, he became one of the founding members of the Royal Society of Edinburgh,[33] and from 1787 to 1789 he occupied the honorary position of Lord Rector of the University of Glasgow.[34] He died in the northern wing of Panmure House in Edinburgh on 17 July 1790 after a painful illness and was buried in the Canongate Kirkyard.[35] On his death bed, Smith expressed disappointment that he had not achieved more.[36]Smith's literary executors were two friends from the Scottish academic world: the physicist and chemist Joseph Black, and the pioneering geologist James Hutton.[37] Smith left behind many notes and some unpublished material, but gave instructions to destroy anything that was not fit for publication.[38] He mentioned an early unpublished History of Astronomy as probably suitable, and it duly appeared in 1795, along with other material such as Essays on Philosophical Subjects.[37][edit] Personality and beliefs[edit] Character James Tassie's enamel paste medallion of Smith provided the model for many engravings and portraits which remain today.[39]Not much is known about Smith's personal views beyond what can be deduced from his published articles. His personal papers were destroyed after his death.[38] He never married[40] and seems to have maintained a close relationship with his mother, with whom he lived after his return from France and who died six years before his own death.[41]Contemporary accounts describe Smith as an eccentric but benevolent intellectual, comically absent minded, with peculiar habits of speech and gait and a smile of "inexpressible benignity".[42] He was known to talk to himself, and had occasional spells of imaginary illness.[36]Smith is often described as a prototypical absent-minded professor.[43] He is reported to have had books and papers stacked up in his study, with a habit he developed during childhood of speaking to himself and smiling in rapt conversation with invisible companions.[43]Various anecdotes have discussed his absentminded nature. In one story, Smith took Charles Townshend on a tour of a tanning factory and while discussing free trade, Smith walked into a huge tanning pit from which he had to be removed.[44] Another episode records that he put bread and butter into a teapot, drank the concoction, and declared it to be the worst cup of tea he ever had. In another example, Smith went out walking and daydreaming in his nightgown and ended up 15 miles (24 km) outside town before nearby church bells brought him back to reality.[43][44][edit] Published worksAdam Smith published a large body of works throughout his life, some of which have shaped the field of economics. Smith's first book, The Theory of Moral Sentiments was written in 1759.[55] It provided the ethical, philosophical, psychological, and methodological underpinnings to Smith's later works, including An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (1776), A Treatise on Public Opulence (1764) (first published in 1937), Essays on Philosophical Subjects (1795), Lectures on Justice, Police, Revenue, and Arms (1763) (first published in 1896), and Lectures on Rhetoric and Belles Lettres.[edit] The Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759)Main article: The Theory of Moral SentimentsIn 1759, Smith published his first work, The Theory of Moral Sentiments. He continued to revise the work throughout his life, making extensive revisions to the final (6th) edition shortly before his death in 1790.[note 2] Although The Wealth of Nations is widely regarded as Smith's most influential work, it has been reported that Smith himself "always considered his Theory of Moral Sentiments a much superior work to his Wealth of Nations".[57] P. J. O'Rourke, author of the commentary On The Wealth of Nations (2007), has agreed, calling Theory of Moral Sentiments "the better book".[58] It was in this work that Smith first referred to the "invisible hand" to describe the apparent benefits to society of people behaving in their own interests.[59]In The Theory of Moral Sentiments, Smith critically examined the moral thinking of the time and suggested that conscience arises from social relationships.[60] His aim in the work is to explain the source of mankind's ability to form moral judgements, in spite of man's natural inclinations toward self-interest. Smith proposes a theory of sympathy in which the act of observing others makes people aware of themselves and the morality of their own behavior. Haakonssen writes that in Smith's theory, "Society is ... the mirror in which one catches sight of oneself, morally speaking."[61]In part because Theory of Moral Sentiments emphasizes sympathy for others while Wealth of Nations famously emphasizes the role of self interest, some scholars have perceived a conflict between these works. As one economic historian observed: "Many writers, including the present author at an early stage of his study of Smith, have found these two works in some measure basically inconsistent."[62] But in recent years most scholars of Adam Smith's work have argued that no contradiction exists. In Theory of Moral Sentiments, Smith develops a theory of psychology in which individuals seek the approval of the "impartial spectator" as a result of a natural desire to have outside observers sympathize with them. Rather than viewing the Wealth of Nations and Theory of Moral Sentiments as presenting incompatible views of human nature, most Smith scholars regard the works as emphasizing different aspects of human nature that vary depending on the situation. The Wealth of Nations draws on situations where man's morality is likely to play a smaller role—such as the laborer involved in pin-making—whereas the Theory of Moral Sentiments focuses on situations where man's morality is likely to play a dominant role among more personal exchanges.The site where Adam Smith wrote the Wealth of Nations[edit] The Wealth of Nations (1776)Main article: The Wealth of NationsThe Wealth of Nations expounds that the free market, while appearing chaotic and unrestrained, is actually guided to produce the right amount and variety of goods by a so-called "invisible hand".[59] Smith opposed any form of economic concentration because it distorts the market's natural ability to establish a price that provides a fair return on land, labor, and capital. He advanced the idea that a market economy would produce a satisfactory outcome for both buyers and sellers, and would optimally allocate society's resources.[63] The image of the invisible hand was previously employed by Smith in Theory of Moral Sentiments, but it has its original use in his essay, "The History of Astronomy". Smith believed that when an individual pursues his self-interest, he indirectly promotes the good of society: "by pursuing his own interest, [the individual] frequently promotes that of the society more effectually than when he intends to promote it."[64] Self-interested competition in the free market, he argued, would tend to benefit society as a whole by keeping prices low, while still building in an incentive for a wide variety of goods and services. Nevertheless, he was wary of businessmen and argued against the formation of monopolies.An often-quoted passage from The Wealth of Nations is:[65]It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own self-interest. We address ourselves, not to their humanity but to their self-love, and never talk to them of our own necessities but of their advantages. The first page of the Wealth of Nations, 1776 London editionValue theory was important in classical theory. Smith wrote that the "real price of every thing ... is the toil and trouble of acquiring it" as influenced by its scarcity. Smith maintained that, with rent and profit, other costs besides wages also enter the price of a commodity.[66] Other classical economists presented variations on Smith, termed the 'labour theory of value'. Classical economics focused on the tendency of markets to move to long-run equilibrium.Adam Smith's advocacy of self-interest based economic exchange did not, however, preclude for him issues of fairness and justice. In Asia, Europeans "by different arts of oppression..have reduced the population of several of the Moluccas,"[67] he wrote, while "the savage injustice of the Europeans" arriving in America, "rendered an event, which ought to have been beneficial to all, ruinous and destructive to several of those unfortunate countries."[68] The Native Americans, "far from having ever injured the people of Europe, had received the first adventurers with every mark of kindness and hospitality." However, "superiority of force" was "so great on the side of the Europeans, that they were enabled to commit with impunity every sort of injustice in those remote countries."[69]Smith also believed that a division of labour would effect a great increase in production. One example he used was the making of pins. One worker could probably make only twenty pins per day. However, if ten people divided up the eighteen steps required to make a pin, they could make a combined amount of 48,000 pins in one day. However, Smith's views on division of labour are not unambiguously positive, and are typically mis-characterized. Smith says of the division of labour:"In the progress of the division of labour, the employment of the far greater part of those who live by labour, that is, of the great body of the people, comes to be confined to a few very simple operations, frequently only one or two. ...The man whose whole life is spent in performing a few simple operations, of which the effects too are, perhaps, always the same, or very nearly the same, has no occasion to exert his understanding, or to exercise his invention in finding out expedients for removing difficulties which never occur. He naturally loses, therefore, the habit of such exertion, and generally becomes as stupid and ignorant as it is possible for a human creature to become. ...His dexterity at his own particular trade seems, in this manner, to be acquired at the expense of his intellectual, social, and martial virtues. ...this is the state into which the labouring poor, that is, the great body of the people, must necessarily fall, unless government takes some pains to prevent it."[70]On labor relations, Smith noted "severity" of laws against worker actions, and contrasted the masters' "clamour" against workers associations, with associations and collusions of the masters which "are never heard by the people" though such actions are "always" and "everywhere" taking place:"We rarely hear, it has been said, of the combinations of masters, though frequently of those of workmen. But whoever imagines, upon this account, that masters rarely combine, is as ignorant of the world as of the subject. Masters are always and everywhere in a sort of tacit, but constant and uniform, combination, not to raise the wages of labour above their actual rate...Masters, too, sometimes enter into particular combinations to sink the wages of labour even below this rate. These are always conducted with the utmost silence and secrecy till the moment of execution; and when the workmen yield, as they sometimes do without resistance, though severely felt by them, they are never heard of by other people" In contrast, when workers combine, "the masters..never cease to call aloud for the assistance of the civil magistrate, and the rigorous execution of those laws which have been enacted with so much severity against the combination of servants, labourers, and journeymen."[71]Adam Smith's burial place in Canongate Kirkyard[edit] Other worksShortly before his death, Smith had nearly all his manuscripts destroyed. In his last years, he seemed to have been planning two major treatises, one on the theory and history of law and one on the sciences and arts. The posthumously published Essays on Philosophical Subjects, a history of astronomy down to Smith's own era, plus some thoughts on ancient physics and metaphysics, probably contain parts of what would have been the latter treatise. Lectures on Jurisprudence were notes taken from Smith's early lectures, plus an early draft of The Wealth of Nations, published as part of the 1976 Glasgow Edition of the works and correspondence of Adam Smith.Other works, including some published posthumously, include Lectures on Justice, Police, Revenue, and Arms (1763) (first published in 1896); A Treatise on Public Opulence (1764) (first published in 1937); and Essays on Philosophical Subjects (1795).

亚当斯密斯英文名

139 评论(12)

洁博利郑少波

1723年亚当斯密出生在苏格兰法夫郡(County Fife)的寇克卡迪(Kirkcaldy)。亚当斯密的父亲也叫Adam Smith,是律师、也是苏格兰的军法官和寇克卡迪的海关监督,在亚当斯密出生前几个月去世;母亲玛格丽特(Margaret)是法夫郡斯特拉森德利(Strathendry)大地主约翰.道格拉斯(John Douglas)的女儿,亚当斯密一生与母亲相依为命,终身未娶。 1740~1746年间,赴牛津大学(Colleges at Oxford)求学,但在牛津并未获得良好的教育,唯一收获是大量阅读许多格拉斯哥大学缺乏的书籍。1751年后,亚当斯密在格拉斯哥大学不仅担任过逻辑学和道德哲学教授,还兼负责学校行政事务,一直到1764年离开为止;这时期中,亚当斯密于1759年出版的《道德情操论》获得学术界极高评价。而后于1768年开始着手著述《国富论》,1773年时认为《国富论》已基本完成,但亚当斯密多花三年时间润饰此书,1776年3月此书出版后引起大众广泛的讨论,影响所及除了英国本地,连欧洲大陆和美洲也为之疯狂,因此世人尊称亚当斯密为“现代经济学之父”和“自由企业的守护神”。

285 评论(11)

品尝滋味real

亚当斯密(Adam Smith,1723~1790),是英国古典政治经济学的主要代表人物之一。他的代表作《国富论》(全称《国民财富的性质和原因的研究》)早以被翻译成十几种文字,全球发行。而他本人也因此被奉为现代西方经济学的鼻祖。亚当斯密出生与苏格兰的克科第的一个海关官员的家庭,14岁考入格拉斯哥大学,学习数学和哲学,17岁时转入牛津大学。值得一提的是,格拉斯哥是当时苏格兰的工业中心,或许亚当.斯密对经济学的兴趣就是在他14岁的时候发生的。他毕业后,于1748年到爱丁堡大学讲授修辞学与文学。1751年返回格拉斯哥大学讲授逻辑学,次年担任道德哲学讲座。他讲的道德哲学包括神学、论理学、法学和政治学四个部分。他的伦理学讲义后来经过修订在1759年作为《道德情操论》出版,为他赢得了声誉。而他关于法学和政治学的讲义包含了贸易、价格、税收等财政经济问题,表明他在这个时期已经开始研究政治经济学。亚当.斯密在格拉斯哥一直居住到1764年,这使他有可能长期实地观察这个工业中心的经济生活。他曾积极参与当地的社会活动,尤其是经济学会的活动,并支持瓦特改进蒸汽机的实验活动。1764年,他辞退了大学教授的职务,担任布克莱公爵的私人教师,并陪同公爵到欧洲大陆旅行。在法国巴黎,他认识了启蒙思想家伏尔泰、重农学派代表魁奈和杜尔阁等名流,这对他的经济学说的形成有很大的影响。1767年,他辞去私人教师的职务,返回家乡克科第埋首于《国富论》的写作。弹指间,白驹过隙,地球已公转十周。1776年,凝聚了亚当.斯密十年心血的《国富论》终于问世。此书一出,极受英国资产阶级的欢迎与褒誉,因为它为实行自由放任的经济政策提供了理论根据。(注:在1688年的“光荣革命”后,英国的经济政策还是以重商主义那一套为主,这实际上是封建残余在经济方面的表现,违背代表时代发展方向的处于工业革命初期的产业资产阶级的自由贸易的要求。)亚当.斯密成了最受欢迎的经济学家,《国富论》的观点成了国会议员的常用论据,甚至连当时的英国首相皮特也自称是斯密的学生。不知不觉间,斯密来到了他一生中最风光得意的时刻。1778年,他出任爱丁堡的海关专员,1787年一度出任格拉斯哥大学的校长,但在经济理论再也没有什么新成就。这究竟是因为他已经来到他所出于的时代所能达到的极限,还是因为“生于忧患,死于安乐”——满足于现状而缺乏进取,就有待后人思考。无论如何,无可否认的是,《国富论》的确是一部划时代的巨著。它概括了古典政治经济学在形成阶段的理论成就,它最早系统地阐述了政治经济学的各个主要学说,它标志着自由资本主义时代的到来。亚当斯密并不是经济学说的最早开拓者,他最著名的思想中有许多也并非新颖独特,但是他首次提出了全面系统的经济学说,为该领域的发展打下了良好的基础。因此完全可以说《国富论》是现代政治经济学研究的起点。该书的伟大成就之一是摒弃了许多过去的错误概念。斯密驳斥了旧的重商学说。这种学说片面强调国家贮备大量金币的重要性。他否决了重农主义者的土地是价值的主要来源的观点,提出了劳动的基本重要性。斯密重点强调劳动分工会引起生产的大量增长,抨击了阻碍工业发展的一整套腐朽的、武断的政治限制。《国富论》的中心思想是看起来似乎杂乱无章的自由市场实际上是个自行调整机制,自动倾向于生产社会最迫切需要的货品种类的数量。例如,如果某种需要的产品供应短缺,其价格自然上升,价格上升会使生产商获得较高的利润,由于利润高,其他生产商也想要生产这种产品。生产增加的结果会缓和原来的供应短缺,而且随着各个生产商之间的竞争,供应增长会使商品的价格降到“自然价格”即其生产成本。谁都不是有目的地通过消除短缺来帮助社会,但是问题却解决了。用斯密的话来说,每个人“只想得到自己的利益”,但是又好象“被一只无形的手牵着去实现一种他根本无意要实现的目的,……他们促进社会的利益,其效果往往比他们真正想要实现的还要好。”(《国富论》,第四卷第二章)但是如果自由竞争受到阻障,那只“无形的手”就不会把工作做得恰到好处。因而斯密相信自由贸易,为坚决反对高关税而申辩。事实上他坚决反对政府对商业和自由市场的干涉。他声言这样的干涉几乎总要降低经济效率,最终使公众付出较高的代价。斯密虽然没有发明“放任政策”这个术语,但是他为建立这个概念所做的工作比任何其他人都多。有些人认为亚当斯密只不过是一位商业利益的辩护士,但是这种看法是不正确的。他经常反复用最强烈的言辞痛斥垄断商的活动,坚决要求将其消灭。斯密对现实的商业活动的认识也并非天真幼稚。《国富论》中记有这样一个典型观察:“同行人很少聚会,但是他们会谈不是策划出一个对付公众的阴谋就是炮制出一个掩人耳目提高物价的计划。”亚当斯密的经济思想体系结构严密,论证有力,使经济思想学派在几十年内就被抛弃了。实际上亚当·斯密把他们所有的优点都吸入进了自己的体系,同时也系统地披露了他们的缺点。斯密的接班人,包括象托马斯·马尔萨斯和大卫·李嘉图这样著名的经济学家对他的体系进行了精心的充实和修正(没有改变基本纲要),今天被称为经典经济学体系。虽然现代经济学说又增加了新的概念和方法,但这些大体说来是经典经济学的自然产物。在一定意义上来说,甚至卡尔·马克思的经济学说(自然不是他的政治学说)都可以看作是经典经济学说的继续。在《国富论》中,斯密在一定程度上预见到了马尔萨斯人口过剩的观点。虽然李嘉图和卡尔·马克思都坚持认为人口负担会阻碍工资高出维持生计的水平(所谓的“工资钢铁定律”),但是斯密指出在增加生产的情况下工资就会增长。事实已经十分清楚地表明斯密在这一点上正确,而李嘉图和马克思是错的。除了斯密观点的正确性及对后来理论家的影响之外就是他对立法和政府政策的影响。《国富论》一书技巧高超,文笔清晰,拥有广泛的读者。斯密反对政府干涉商业和商业事务、赞成低关税和自由贸易的观点在整个十九世纪对政府政策都有决定性的影响。事实上他对这些政策的影响今天人们仍能感觉出来。自从斯密以来经济学有了突飞猛进的发展以致他的一些思想已被搁置一边,因而人们容易低估他的重要性。但实际上他是使经济学说成为一门系统科学的主要创立人,因而是人类思想史上的主要人物。

304 评论(15)

猪小七ice

1、亚当·斯密(Adam Smith,1723年6月5日—1790年7月17日),出生在苏格兰法夫郡(County Fife)的寇克卡迪(Kirkcaldy),英国经济学家、哲学家、作家,经济学的主要创立者。亚当·斯密强调自由市场、自由贸易以及劳动分工,被誉为“古典经济学之父”“现代经济学之父”。2、1723年6月5日,亚当·斯密出生于苏格兰法夫郡一个只有1500人左右的小镇寇克卡迪(Kirkcaldy)。幼年的斯密聪明好学,14岁就进入格拉斯哥大学(University of Glasgow),主修拉丁语、希腊语、数学以及道德哲学。在格拉斯哥学习期间,哲学教授弗兰西斯·哈奇森的自由主义精神给予斯密启发。3、1740年,斯密获得了奖学金,进入牛津大学学习,1746年毕业后回到故乡柯卡尔迪。1748年,斯密开始在爱丁堡大学担任讲师,主讲英国文学,几年后又开始讲授经济学课程。4、1751年,斯密回到母校格拉斯哥任教授,主讲逻辑学和道德哲学。在格拉斯哥大学任职期间,斯密公开发表经济自由主义的主张,形成了自己的经济学观点。5、1759年,斯密的第一部著作《道德情操论》出版。1764年,斯密受布克莱(Buccleuch)公爵之邀,离开格拉斯哥大学,到欧洲大陆旅行。旅行的经历以及在旅行过程中同许多大陆学者的交往,促使斯密经济理论走向成熟,尤其是重农主义的经济学家魁奈对他影响很大。三年后,斯密回到伦敦,被选为英国皇家学会会员。为了完成自己的研究工作,斯密回到故乡寇克卡迪,开始潜心撰写经济学著作。6、1776年,这部写作历时六年,修改三年的经济学著作《国民财富的性质和原因的研究》(即《国富论》)终于完成。它的发表,标志着古典自由主义经济学的正式诞生。在写作《国富论》的过程中,斯密积劳成疾。自1784年开始,他健康状况持续恶化。但斯密依然笔耕不辍,继续写作两部关于哲学和经济学的著作。7、1787年,斯密应邀去伦敦为英国内阁成员讲授经济学,同年11月,又被推荐担任母校格拉斯哥大学的校长。1790年7月17日,斯密逝世_8、斯密在临终前,他坚持将未完成的十几部手稿付之一炬。在他逝世后,后人根据他的学生所记的笔记,1796年整理出版了《正义、警察、岁入和军备讲稿》,其他遗稿也陆续整理出版,包括1793年的《哲学问题论集》,1795年的《天文学史》等等。

322 评论(10)

相关问答